Wednesday, April 23, 2014

AdamSmith. AnInquiryIntoTheNatureAndCausesOf. WealthOfTheNationsThe. Summary. Divided by the author. BookOne. ModernLibrary.1994.



1)      Of the Causes of Improvement in the productive Powers of Labour, and of the Order according to which its Produce is naturally distributed among the different Ranks of the People
a)      Of the Division of Labour
·        Division of labour is the great cause of its increased powers, as may be better understood from a particular example,
·        such as pinmaking.
·        The effect is similar in all trades and also in the division of employments.
·        The advantage is due to three circumstances,
·        (1) improved dexteiry,
·        (2) saving of time,
·        and (3) application of machinery, invented by workmen,
·        or by machinemakers and philosophers.
·        Hence the universal opulence of a well-governed society,
·        even the day-labourer’s coat being the produce of a vast number of workmen.
b)      Of the Principle which gives Occasion to the Division of Labour
·        The division of labour arises from a propensity in human nature in exchange.
·        This propensity is found in man alone.
·        It is encouraged by self-interest and leads to division of labour,
·        thus giving rise to differences of talent more important than the natural differences,
·        and rendering those differences useful.
c)      That the Division of Labour is limited by the Extent of the Market
·        Division of labour is limited by the extent of the power of exchanging.
·        Various trades cannot be carried on except in towns.
·        Water-carriage widens the market,
·        and so the first improvements are on the sea-coast or navigable rivers,
·        for example among the ancient nations on the Mediterranean coast.
·        Improvements first took place in Egypt,
·        Bengal and China;
·        while Africa, Tartary and Siberia, and also Bavaria, Austria and Hungary are backward.
d)      Of the Origin and Use of Money
·        Division of labour being established, every man lives by exchanging.
·        Difficulties of barter lead to the selection of one commodity as money,
·        for example, cattle, salt, shells, cod, tobacco, sugar, leather and nails.
·        Metals were eventually preferred because durable and divisible.
·        Iron, copper, gold and silver,
·        were at first used in unstamped bars,
·        and afterwards stamped to show quantity and fineness;
·        stamps to show fineness being introduced first,
·        and coinage to show weight later.
·        The names of coins originally expressed their weight.
·        The next inquiry is what rules determine exchangeable value.
·        Value may mean either value in use or value in exchange.
·        Three questions,
·        (1) wherein consists the real price of commodities,
·        (2) what are the different parts of this price, (3) why the market price sometimes diverges from this price,
·        will be answered in the next three chapters.
e)      Of the real and nominal Price of Commodities, or of their Price in Labour, and their Price in Money
·        Labour is the real measure of exchangeable value,
·        and the first price paid for all things.
·        Wealth is power of purchasing labour.
·        But value is not commonly estimated by labour, because labour is difficult to measure,
·        and commodities are more frequently exchanged for other commodities,
·        especially money, which is therefore more frequently used in estimating value.
·        But gold and silver vary in value, sometimes costing more and sometimes less labour, whereas equal labour always means equal sacrifice to the labourer,
·        although the employer regards labour as varying in value.
·        So regarded, labour has a real and a nominal price.
·        The distinction between real and nominal is sometimes useful in practice,
·        since the amount of metal in coins tends to diminish,
·        and the value of gold and silver to fall.
·        English rents reserved in money have fallen to a fourth since 1586.
·        and similar Scotch and French rents almost to nothing.
·        Corn rents are more stable than money rents,
·        but liable to much larger annual variations,
·        so that labour is the only universal standard.
·        But in ordinary transactions money is sufficient,
·        being perfectly accruate at the same time and place,
·        and the only thing to be considered in transactions between distant places.
·        So it is no wonder that money price has been more attended to.
·        In this work corn prices will sometimes be used.
·        Several metals have been coined, but only one is used as the standard, and that usually the one first used in commerce,
·        as the Romans used copper,
·        and modern European nations silver.
·        The standard metal originally was the only legal tender,
·        later the proportion between the values of the two metals is declared by law, and both are legal tender, the distinction between them ceasing to be of importance,
·        except when a change is made in the regulated proportion.
·        During the continuance of a regulated proportion, the value of the most precious metal regulates the value of the whole coinage, as in Great Britain,
·        where the reformation of the gold coin has raised the value of the silver coin.
·        Silver is rated below its value in England.
·        Locke’s explanation of the high price of silver bullion is wrong.
·        If the silver coin were reformed, it would be melted.
·        Silver ought to be rated higher and should not be legal tender for more than a guinea.
·        If it were properly rated, silver bullion would fall below the mint price without any recognition.
·        A seignorage would prevent melting and discourage exportation.
·        Fluctuations in the market price of gold and silver are due to ordinary commercial causes, but steady divergence from mint price is due to the state of the coin.
·        The price of goods is adjusted to the actual contents of the coinage.
f)       Of the component Parts of the Price of Commodities
·        Quantity of labour is originally the only rule of value,
·        allowance being made for superior hardship,
·        and for uncommon dexterity and ingenuity.
·        The whole produce then belongs to the labourer,
·        but when stock is used, something must be given for the profits of the undertaker, and the value of work resolves itself into wages and profits.
·        Profits are not merely wages of inspection and direction.
·        The labourer shares with the employer, and labour alone no longer regulates value.
·        When land has all become private property, rent constitutes a third component part of the price of most commodities.
·        The real value of all three parts is measured by labour.
·        In an improved society all three parts are generally present,
·        for example, in corn,
·        in flour or meal,
·        and in flax.
·        Rent is a smaller proportion in highly manufactured commodities.
·        A few commodities have only two or even one of the three component parts.
·        But all must have at least one,
·        and the price of the whole annual produce resolves itself into wages, profits and rent,
·        which are the only original kinds of revenue.
·        They are sometimes confounded,
·        for example, a gentleman farmer’s rent is called profit,
·        a common farmer’s wages are called profit,
·        and so are an independent manufacturer’s wages,
·        while the rent and profit of a gardener cultivating his own land are considered earnings of labour.
·        A great part of the annual produce goes to the idle; the proportion regulates the increase or diminution of the produce.
g)      Of the natural and market Price of Commodities
·        Ordinary are average rates of wages, profit,
·        and rent
·        may be called natural rates,
·        to pay which a commodity is sold as its natural price,
·        or for what it really costs, which includes profit,
·        since no one will go on selling without profit.
·        Market price
·        is regulated by the quantity brought to market and the effectual demand.
·        When the quantity brought falls short of the effectual demand, the market price rises above the natural;
·        when it exceeds the effectual demand the market price falls below the natural;
·        when it is just equal to the effectual demand the market and natural price coincide.
·        It naturally suits itself to the effectual demand.
·        When it exceeds that demand, some of the components parts of its price are below their natural rate;
·        when it falls short, some of the component parts are above their natural rate.
·        Natural price is the central price to which actual price gravitate.
·        Industry suits itself to the effectual demand,
·        but the quantity produced by a given amount of industry sometimes flunctuates.
·        The fluctuations fall on wages and profit more than on rent,
·        affecting them in different proportions according to the supply of commodities and labour.
·        But market price may be kept above natural for a long time,
·        in consequence of want of general knowledge of high profits,
·        or in consequence of secrets in manufactures,
·        which may operate for long periods,
·        or in consequence of scarcity of peculiar soils,
·        which may continue for ever.
·        A monopoly has the same effect as a trade secret,
·        the price of monopoly being the highest which can be got.
·        Corporation privileges, etc., are enlarged monopolies.
·        Market price is seldom long below natural price,
·        though apprenticeship and corporation laws sometimes reduce wages much below the natural rate for a certain period.
·        Natural price varies with the natural rate of wages, profit and rent.
·        Wages will be dealt with in chapter vii.,
·        profit in chapter ix.,
·        differences of wages and profit in chapter x.,
·        and rent in chapter xi.
h)      Of the Wages of Labour
·        Produce is the natural wages of labour.
·        Originally the whole belonged to the labourer.
·        If this had continued, all things would have become cheaper,
·        though in appearance many things might have become dearer.
·        This state was ended by the appropriation of land and accumulation of stock,
·        rent being the first deduction,
·        and profit the second, both in agriculture,
·        and other arts and manufacturers.
·        The independent workman gets profits as well as wages,
·        but this case is infrequent.
·        Wages depend on contract between masters and workmen.
·        The masters have the advantage,
·        though less is heard of masters’s combinations than of workmen’s.
·        But masters cannot reduce wages below a certain rate, namely, subsistence for a man and something over for a family.
·        Wages may be considerably above this rate,
·        when there is an increasing demand for labourers,
·        which is caused by an increase of the funds destined for the payment of wages. The funds consist of
·        surplus revenue,
·        and surplus stock.
·        The demand for labourers therefore increases with the increase of national wealth.
·        High wages are occasioned by the increase, not by the actual greatness of national wealth.
·        North America is more thriving than England.
·        Wages are not high in a stationary country however rich.
·        China is not going backwards and labourers there keep up their numbers.
·        In a declining country this would not be the case.
·        In Great Britain wages are above the lowest rate,
·        since (1) there is difference between winter and summer wages,
·        (2) wages do not fluctuate with the price of provisions,
·        (3) wages vary more from place to place than the price of provisions,
·        and (4) frequently wages and the price of provisions vary in opposite directions, as grain is cheaper and wages are higher in England than in Scotland;
·        and in last century grain was dearer and wages were lower than in this;
·        while other necessaries and conveniencies have also become cheaper.
·        High earnings of labour are an advantage to the society.
·        Poverty does not prevent births,
·        but is unfavourable to the rearing of children,
·        and so restrains multiplication,
·        while the liberal reward of labour encourages it.
·        as the wear and tear of the free man must be paid for just like that of the slave, though not so extravagantly.
·        High wages increase population.
·        The progressive state is the best for the labouring poor.
·        High wages encourage industry.
·        The opinion that cheap years encourage idleness is erroneous.
·        Wages are high in cheap years,
·        and low in dear years,
·        so that masters commend dear years.
·        Messance shows that in some French manufactures more is produced in cheap years.
·        No connexion is visible between dearness or cheapness of the years and the variations in Scotch linen and Yorkshire woollen manufacturers.
·        The produce depends on other circumstances, and more of it escapes being reckoned in cheap years.
·        There is, however, a connexion between the price of labour and that of provisions.
·        In years of plenty there is a greater demand for labour,
·        and in years of scarcity a less demand,
·        and the effect of variations in the price of provisions is thus counterbalanced.
·        Increase of wages increases prices, but the case of increased wages tends to diminish prices.
i)       Of the Profits of Stock
·        Profits depend on increase and decrease of wealth,
·        falling with the increase of wealth.
·        The rate is difficult to ascertain,
·        but may be inferred from the rate of interest,
·        which has fallen in England,
·        while wealth has been increasing.
·        Profits are lower in towns, where there is much stock, than in the country, where there is little.
·        Interest is higher in Scotland, a poor country, than in England.
·        So too in France, a country probably less rich than England,
·        but lower in Holland, which is richer than England.
·        In the peculiar case of new colonies high wages and high profits go together, but profits gradually diminish.
·        New territories and trades may raise profits even in a country advancing in riches.
·        Diminution of capital stock raises profits.
·        In a country as rich as it possibly could be, profits as well as wages would be very low,
·        but there has never yet been any such country.
·        Interest is raised by defective enforcement of contracts,
·        and by prohibition.
·        The lowest rate of profit must be more than enough to compensate losses,
·        and so must the lowest rate of interest.
·        In a country as rich as it possibly could be interest would be so low that only the wealthiest people could live on it.
·        The highest rate of profit would eat up all rent and leave only wages.
·        The proportion of interest to profit rises and falls with the rate of profit.
·        Countries with low profits can sell as cheap as those with low wages; and in reality high profits tend to raise prices more than high wages.
j)       Of Wages and Profit in the different Employments of Labour and Stock
·        Advantages and disadvantages tend to equality where there is perfect liberty.
·        Actual differences of pecuniary wages and profits are due partly to counterbalancing circumstances and partly to want of perfect liberty.
i)       Inequalities arising from the Nature of the Employments themselves
·        There are five counterbalancing circumstances:
·        (1) Wages vary with the agreeableness of the employment.
·        Some very agreeable employments are exceedingly ill paid.
·        The same thing is true of profits.
·        (2) Wages vary with the cost of learning the business.
·        The cost of apprenticeship accounts for the wages of manufacturers being higher than those of country labourers.
·        Education for liberal professions is more costly and the pecuniary recompense consequently higher. Profits are not much affected by this circumstance.
·        (3) Wages vary with constancy of employment.
·        Constancy does not affect profits.
·        (4) Wages vary with the trust to be reposed.
·        Profits are unaffected by trust.
·        (5) Wages vary with the probability of success.
·        Law and similar professions are nevertheless crowded.
·        Public admiration makes a part of the reward of superior abilities,
·        except in the peculiar case of players, opera-singers, &c.
·        The greater part of men have an over-weening conceit of their abilities:
·        lotteries show that the chance of gain is overvalued.
·        and the moderate profit of insurers shows that the chance of loss is undervalued.
·        Young people are particularly prone to overvalue the chance of gain and undervalue the risk of loss.
·        For this reason soldiers are poorly paid,
·        and sailors not much better.
·        Dangers which can be surmounted attract, though mere unwholesomeness repels.
·        Profits vary with certainty of return.
·        Profits are less unequal than wages, and their inequality is often only due to the inclusion of wages,
·        as in the case of the profit of an apothecary,
·        or country grocer.
·        The greater difference between retail and wholesale profits in town than country is due to the same cause.
·        The lesser rate of profit in towns yields larger fortunes, but these mostly arise from speculation.
·        The five circumstances thus counterbalance difference of pecuniary gains,
·        but three things are necessary as well as perfect freedom:
·        (1) the employments must be well known and long established,
·        since new trades yield higher wages,
·        and higher profits:
·        (2) the employments must be in their natural state,
·        since the demand for labour in each employment varies from time to time
·        and profits fluctuate with the price of the commodity produced:
·        and (3) the employments must be the principal employment of those who occupy them, since people maintained by one employment will work cheap at another, like the Scotch cotters,
·        Shetland knitters,
·        Scotch linen spinners,
·        and London lodging house keepers.
ii)      Inequalities occasioned by the Policy of Europe
·        The policy of Europe occasions more important inequalities
·        in three ways:
·        (1) It restricts competition in some employments,
·        principally by giving exclusive privileges to corporations,
·        which require long apprenticeship and limit the number of apprentices.
·        Seven years is the usual period of apprenticeship.
·        The Statute of Apprenticeship, which reduced it everywhere in England, has been confined to market towns,
·        and to trades existing when it was passed.
·        The term varies in France,
·        and Scotland, where the regulations are less oppressive.
·        All such regulations are as impertinent as oppressive.
·        Long apprenticeships are no security against bad work,
·        and do not form young people to industry.
·        Apprenticeships were unknown to the ancients.
·        Long apprenticeships are altogether unnecessary.
·        Corporations were established to keep up prices and consequently wages and profit;
·        by means of which the towns gained at the expense of the country,
·        being enabled to get the produce of a larger quantity of country labour in exchange for the produce of a smaller quantity of their own,
·        as the exports of a town are the real price of its imports.
·        That town industry is better paid is shown by the large fortunes made in it.
·        Combination is easy to the inhabitants of a town,
·        and difficult to those of the country, who are dispersed and not governed by the corporation spirit. No apprenticeship is prescribed for farming, through a difficult art,
·        or for the inferior branches of country labour, which require more skill than most mechanic trades.
·        The superiority of town industry is enhanced by other regulations, such as high duties on foreign manufactures.
·        The superiority has declined in Great Britain.
·        Meetings of people in the same trade ought not to be facilitated,
·        as by registration of traders,
·        by the establishment of funds for the sick, widows and orphans,
·        or by incorporation.
·        Corporations are unnecessary, and corrupt the workmen.
·        (2) The policy of Europe increases competition in some trades.
·        It cheapens the education of the clergy and thereby reduces their earnings;
·        so that it is only the great benefices, etc., which support the honour of the English and Roman Catholic Churches.
·        The same cause, if present, would lower the reward of lawyers and physicians,
·        as it has done that of men of letters,
·        and that of teachers,
·        who were much better paid in ancient times.
·        Perhaps this cheapness of teaching is no disadvantage to the public.
·        (3) The policy of Europe obstructs the free circulation of labour.
·        Apprenticeship and corporation privileges obstruct circulation from employment to employment and from place to place.
·        So that the changes of employment necessary to equalise wages are prevented.
·        What obstructs the circulation of labour also obstructs that of stock.
·        In England the circulation of labour is further obstructed by the poor law.
·        Each parish was to support its own poor under 43 Eliz., c. 2;
·        these were determined by 13 and 14 Car. II. to be such as had resided forty days, within which time, however, a new inhabitant might be removed.
·        Notice in writing was required from the new inhabitant by I and James II.
·        Such notice was to be published in church under 3 W. III.
·        There were four other ways of gaining a settlement,
·        two of which were impossible to all poor men,
·        and the other two to all married men,
·        and to all independent workmen.
·        Certificates were invented to enable persons to reside in a parish without being immediately removable and without gaining a settlement.
·        Certificates were required by the new parish but refused by the old.
·        The courts declined to force overseers to give a certificate.
·        This law is the cause of the very unequal price of labour in England,
·        and an evident violation of natural liberty, though tamely submitted to.
·        Wages were anciently rated by law or by justices of peace.
·        London taylors’s wages are still rated by law.
·        Attempts were also made to regulate profits by fixing prices, and the assize of bread still remains.
·        The inequalities of wages and profits are not much affected by the advancing or declining state of the society.
k)      Of the Rent of Land
·        Rent is the produce which is over what is necessary to pay the farmer ordinary profit.
·        It is not merely interest on stock laid out in improvements,
·        and is sometimes obtained for land incapable of improvement, such as rocks where kelp grows;
·        and for the opportunity to fish.
·        It is therefore a monopoly price.
·        Whether particular parts of produce fetch a price sufficient to yield a rent depends on the demand.
·        Some parts are always in sufficient demand; others sometimes are and sometimes are not.
·        Wages and profit are causes of price; rent is an effect.
·        The chapter is divided into three parts.
i)       Of the Produce of Land which always affords Rent
·        Food can always purchase as much labour as it can maintain.
·        Almost all land produces more than enough food to maintain the labour and pay the profits, and therefore yields rent.
·        The rent varies with situation as well as with fertility.
·        Good roads, etc., diminish differences of rent.
·        Corn land yields a larger supply of food after maintaining labour than pasture.
·        In early times meat is cheaper than bread,
·        but later on it becomes dearer,
·        and pasture yields as good a rent as corn land,
·        and sometimes a greater one,
·        as in the neighbourhood of a great town.
·        or all over a populous country which imports corn, such as Holland and ancient Italy,
·        and occasionally in a country where enclosure is unusual.
·        Ordinarily the rent of corn land regulates that of pasture.
·        Improved methods of feeding cattle lower meat in proportion to bread.
·        The price of meat was higher at the beginning of the seventeenth century
·        than in 1763-4;
·        whereas wheat was cheaper.
·        The rent and profit of corn land and pasture regulate those of all other land.
·        The apparently greater rent or profit of some other kinds is only interest on greater expense,
·        as in hop, and fruit gardens;
·        kitchen gardens;
·        and vineyards.
·        Land fitted for a particular produce may have a monopoly,
·        such as that which produces wine of a particular flavour,
·        or the West Indian sugar colonies,
·        and in a less degree the tobacco plantations of Virginia and Maryland.
·        So the rent of cultivated land producing food regulates that of most of the rest,
·        and in Europe the rent of corn land regulates that of other cultivated land producing food.
·        If the common food was such as to produce a greater surplus, rent would be higher:
·        for example, rice,
·        or potatoes.
·        Wheat is probably a better food than oats,
·        but not than potatoes.
·        Potatoes however, are perishable.
ii)      Of the Produce of Land which sometimes does, and sometimes does not, afford Rent
·        The materials of cloathing and lodging, at first super-abundant, come in time to afford a rent.
·        For example, hides and wool,
·        stone and timber.
·        Population depends on food;
·        so the demand for the materials of cloathing and lodging is increased by greater ease of obtaining food,
·        which thus makes them afford rent.
·        They do not, however, even then always afford rent:
·        for example, some coal-mines are too barren to afford rent,
·        or too disadvantageously situated.
·        The price of coal is kept down by that of wood,
·        which varies with the state of agriculture.
·        But in the coal countries coal is everywhere much below this price.
·        The lowest possible price is that which only replaces stock with profits.
·        Rent forms a smaller proportion of the price of coal than of that of most other rude produce.
·        The situation of a metallic mine is less important than that of a coal mine,
·        metals from all parts of the world being brought into competition.
·        Rent has therefore a small share in the price of metals.
·        Tin and lead mines pay a sixth in Cornwall and Scotland.
·        The silver mines of Peru formerly paid a fifth,
·        and now only a tenth,
·        while profits are small.
·        Mining is encouraged in Peru by the interest of the sovereign.
·        The gold mines of Peru now pay only a twentieth in rent.
·        The lowest price of the precious metals must replace stock with ordinary profits,
·        but their highest price is determined by their scarcity.
·        The demand for them arises from their utility and beauty:
·        and the merit of beauty is enhanced by their scarcity.
·        The demand for precious stones arises altogether from their beauty enhanced by their scarcity.
·        The rent of mines of precious metals and precious stones is in proportion to their relative and not to their absolute fertility.
·        Abundant supplies would add little to the wealth of the world.
·        But in estates above ground both produce and rent are regulated by absolute fertility.
·        Abundance of food raises the value of other produce.
iii)     Of the Variations in the Proportion between the respective Values of that Sort of Produce which always affords Rent, and of that which sometimes does and sometimes does not afford Rent
·        The general course of progress is for produce other than food to become dearer,
·        but there are interruptions,
·        as in the case of silver,
·        when new fertile mines are discovered.
·        Silver would grow dearer in the general progress of improvement,
·        but might grow cheaper if some accident increased the supply for many years together:
·        or remain stationary if demand and supply increased equally.
·        These three things have happened during the last 400 years.
(1)    Digression concerning the Variations in the Value of Silver during the Course of the Four last Centuries
(a)    First Period
·        From 1350 to 1570 silver gradually fell.
·        In 1350 wheat ws 4 oz. of silver per quarter,
·        and was not less than that at the beginning of the century,
·        and for some time before.
·        From that it sank gradually to 2 oz. at the beginning of the sixteenth century and remained at that till 1570.
·        The same fall has been observed in France.
·        It may have been due to the increase of demand for silver or to a diminution of supply.
·        Most writers, however, have supposed that the value of silver continually fell.
·        They have been misled in their observations on the price of corn, (1) by confusing conversion prices with market prices;
·        (2) by the slovenly transcription of ancient statutes of assize;
·        or by misunderstandings of those statutes;
·        and (3) by attributing too much importance to excessively low prices.
·        The figures at the end of the chapter confirm this account.
·        Sometimes the value of silver has been measured by the price of cattle, poultry, etc. But the low price of these things shows their cheapness, not the dearness of silver,
·        for labour is the real measure.
·        Cattle, poultry, etc., are produced by very different quantities of labour at different times,
·        whereas corn scarcely varies at all,
·        and also regulates the money price of labour.
·        The authors were also misled by the notion that silver falls in value as its quantity increases.
·        Increases of quantity arising from greater abundance of the mines is connected with diminution of value,
·        but increase of quantity resulting from the increased wealth of a country is not.
·        Gold and silver are dearer in a rich country,
·        as may be shown by comparing China with Europe and Scotland with England as to the price of subsistence.
·        Gold and silver are cheapest among the poorest nations.
·        The fact that corn is dearer in towns due to its dearness there, not to the cheapness of silver,
·        and this is true also in Holland, Genoa, etc.
·        So no increase of silver due to the increase of wealth could have reduced its value.
(b)    Second Period
·        No doubt exists as to the second period,
·        silver sank, and a quarter of corn came to be worth 6 oz. or 8 oz. of silver.
·        This was owing to the discovery of the abundant American mines.
·        Wheat rose at Windosr market.
(c)    Third Period
·        The effect of the discovery of the American mines was complete about 1636.
·        From 1637 to 1700 there was a very slight rise of wheat at Windsor,
·        due to the civil war,
·        the bounty on the exportation of corn,
·        and the clipping and wearing of the coin,
·        which was then much greater than in the present century.
·        Moreover the bounty has been long enough in existence to produce any possible effect in lowering the price of corn.
·        Silver has risen somewhat since the beginning of the century, and the rise began before;
·        as is shown by Mr. King’s calculations.
·        Apart from its effect in extending tillage, the bounty raises the price of corn, both in times of plenty and of scarcity.
·        It is said to have extended tillage (and so to have reduced the price), but the rise of silver has not been peculiar to England.
·        The alteration should be regarded as a rise of silver rather than a fall of corn.
·        The recent high price of corn is merely the effect of unfavourable seasons.
·        The bounty kept up the price between 1741 and 1750.
·        The sudden change at 1750 was due to accidental variation of the seasons.
·        The rise in the price of labour has been due to increase of demand for labour, not to a diminution in the value of silver.
·        The decrease in the rent and profit of mines of gold and silver.
·        has been stayed by the gradual enlargement of the market,
·        (1) in Europe.
·        (2) in America itself,
·        and (3) in the East Indies,
·        where the value of gold and silver was, and still is, higher than in Europe.
·        The supply of silver must provide for waste as well as increase of plate and coin.
·        Waste is considerable.
·        Six millions of gold and silver are imported at Cadiz and Lisbon,
·        as shown by Magens,
·        Raynal,
·        and other authors.
·        This is not the whole of the annual supply, but by far the greater part.
·        Brass and iron increase, but we do not expect them to fall in value. Why then gold and silver?
·        In consequence of their durability the metals, especially gold and silver, vary little in value from year to year.
(2)    Variations in the Proportion between the respective Values of Gold and Silver
·        After the discovery of the American mines silver fell in proportion to gold.
·        It is higher in the East.
·        Magens seems to think the proportion of value should be the same as the proportion of quantity,
·        but this is absurd.
·        The whole of a cheap commodity is commonly worth more than the whole of a dear one, and this is the case with silver and gold.
·        Gold is nearer its lowest possible price than silver.
·        Diamonds are nearer still.
·        It may be necessary to reduce still further the tax on silver in Spanish America.
·        The greater cost of raising silver must lead to an increase of its price, or a reduction of the tax upon it, or both.
·        The reduction of the tax in the past makes silver at least 10 per cent, lower than it would otherwise have been.
·        Silver has probably risen somewhat in the present century.
·        The annual consumption must at length equal the annual importation,
·        and will then accomodate itself to changes in the importation.
(3)    Grounds of the Suspicion that the Value of Silver still continues to decrease
·        Gold and silver are supposed to be still falling because they are increasing in quantity and some sorts of rude produce are rising.
·        It has already been shown that the increase of the metals need not diminish their value:
·        and the rise of cattle, etc., is due to a rise in their real price, not to a fall of silver.
(4)    Different Efforts of the Progress of Improvement upon three different Sorts of rude Produce
·        The real price of three sorts of rude produce rises in the progress of improvement:
(a)    First Sort
·        (1) The sort which cannot be multiplied by human industry, such as game.
(b)    Second Sort
·        (2) The sort which can be multiplied at will, e.g. cattle, poultry.
·        When it becomes profitable to cultivate land to yield food for cattle, the price of cattle cannot go higher.
·        It must go to this height in order to secure complete cultivation.
·        Consequently new colonies are poorly cultivated.
·        Cattle are the first of this second sort of rude produce to bring in the price necessary to secure cultivation,
·        and venison is the last;
·        other things are intermediate,
·        such as poultry,
·        hogs,
·        milk, butter and cheese.
·        The rise of price, being necessary for good cultivation, should be regarded with satisfaction.
·        It is due not to a fall of silver but to a rise in the real price of the produce.
(c)    Third Sort
·        (3) The sort of regard to which the efficacy of industry is limited or uncertain,
·        e.g. wool and hides, which are appendages to other sorts of produce.
·        Wool and hides in early times have a larger market open to them than butcher’s-meat.
·        In thinly inhabited countries the wool and hide are more valuable in proportion to the carcase.
·        In the progress of improvement the wool and hide should rise, though not so much as the carcase.
·        But in England wool has fallen since 1339.
·        This has been caused by artificial regulations.
·        The real price of hides at present is somewhat lower than in the fifteenth century,
·        but their average price during the present century is probably higher.
·        They are not so easily transported as wool,
·        and tanners have not been so much favoured by legislation as clothiers.
·        Regulations which sink the price of wool or hides in an improved country raise the price of meat,
·        but not in an unimproved country.
·        The Union sank the price of Scotch wool, while it raised the price of Scotch meat.
·        The efficacy of industry in increasing wool and hides is both limited and uncertain.
·        The same thing is true of fish, which naturally rise in the progress of improvement.
·        The connexion of success in fishing with the state of improvement is uncertain.
·        In increasing minerals the efficacy of industry is not limited but uncertain.
·        The quantity of the precious metals in a country depends on its power of purchasing and the fertility of the mines.
·        So far as it depends on the former circumstance the real price is likely to rise with improvement;
·        so far as it depends on the latter circumstance the real price will vary with the fertility of the mines,
·        which has no connexion with the state of industry.
(5)    Conclusion of the Digression concerning the Variations in the Value of Silver
·        The high value of the precious metals is no proof of poverty and barbarism,
·        but the low price of cattle, poultry, game, &c., is a proof of poverty of barbarism.
·        A rise of price due entirely to degradation of silver would affect all goods equally, but corn has risen much less than other provisions,
·        and has indeed been somewhat lower in 1701-64 than in 1637-1700
·        while its recent high price has been due only to bad seasons.
·        The distinction between a rise of prices and a fall in the value of silver is not useless:
·        it affords an easy proof of the prosperity of the country,
·        and may be of use in regulating the wages of the inferior servants of the state.
·        The poor are more distressed by the artificial rise of some manufactures than by the natural rise of rude produce other than corn.
(6)    Effects of the Progress of Improvement upon the real Price of Manufactures
·        But the natural effect of improvement is to diminish the price of manufactures.
·        In a few manufactures the rise in the price of raw material counter-balances improvement in execution,
·        but in other cases price falls considerably.
·        Since 1600 this has been most remarkable in manufactures made of the coarser metals.
·        Clothing has not fallen much in the same period,
·        but very considerably since the fifteenth century.
·        Fine cloth has fallen to less than one-third of its price in 1487,
·        and coarse cloth has fallen to less than one half of its price in 1463.
·        Hose have fallen very considerably since 1463,
·        when they were made of common cloth.
·        The machinery for making cloth has been much improved,
·        which explains the fall of price.
·        The coarse manufacture was a household one,
·        but the fine was carried on in Flanders by people who subsisted on it, and was subject to customs duty,
·        which explains why the coarse was in those times lower in proportion to the fine.
(7)    Conclusion of the Chapter
·        Every improvement in the circumstances of society raises rent.
·        Extension of improvement and cultivation raises it directly,
·        and so does the rise in the price of cattle, &c.
·        Improvement which reduce the price of manufactures raise it indirectly,
·        and so does every increase in the quantity of useful labour employed.
·        The contrary circumstances lower rent.
·        There are three parts of produce and three original orders of society.
·        The interest of the proprietors of land is inseparably connected with the general interest of the society.
·        So also is that of those who live by wages,
·        but the interest of those who live by profit has not the same connexion with the general interest of the society.

No comments:

Post a Comment